The Economics of Truth
- Aditya Agrawal
- Sep 10
- 4 min read
Accurate news reporting is a public good. But does it follow that news agencies should be funded through taxation? This question is no longer simply theoretical; it sits at the heart of how societies, economies, and markets function in the twenty-first century. The definition of modern media has changed as much as the media itself in recent years, and so too have the public’s expectations. Society’s evolving stature has fanned an already heated flame. It has developed a thirst for unbiased, accurate reporting and straightforward factual information that offers a real picture of the world rather than a sugar-coated fallacy.

From an economic perspective, a public good is a commodity that generates positive externalities for society. Correct information is not merely a tool for personal decision-making. It allows modern citizens to break free from the fallacies they encounter daily and make informed choices that maximise private benefit alongside a greater social benefit. Accurate information helps us choose careers, healthcare, and financial services. A striking example is India, the world’s largest democracy, where millions of citizens thirst for reliable political information every five years to determine the nation’s future.
Accurate reporting also profoundly influences national and global markets. Investor sentiment is shaped by credible news, boosting stock markets and fostering a stable financial atmosphere. Media thus plays a dual role: informing households and guiding institutional investors. It functions as both a financial stabiliser and a policy signal. At the same time, the media operates as a bridge between ordinary citizens and policymakers. It sets the stage for political discourse, frames debates on unemployment, inflation, and GDP growth, and pressures governments to act. As economic models assume, the citizen requires near-perfect information not only to maximise private benefit but also to contribute to the social optimum.

Yet the prevailing media model exhibits glaring deficiencies. The 2020 pandemic, apart from crippling public life, left robust news outlets financially vulnerable. Free media contracted, uncensored journalism weakened, and censorship re-emerged. In economic terms, this has created market failure: demand for unbiased information remains high, but supply has diminished. Globally, this financial fragility has left outlets open to unhealthy influences, state pressure, or private monopolisation. History is littered with reminders. Nazi Germany’s propaganda machine between 1933 and 1935 weaponised mass media to suffocate public discourse, challenging Habermas’s theory of the media as a “public sphere.” Circulation declined by 11 per cent annually, proof that repression diminishes both democratic health and economic vibrancy. Similar strategies persist in North Korea, Russia, and parts of the Middle East, where governments align all media with the state narrative. The economic cost of censorship is severe: polarised societies, underground economies of information, and stifled innovation.

Article 19 of the Universal Declaration of Human Rights guarantees freedom of opinion and expression. Any censorship or adulteration violates this right, restricting the ability to seek and impart information. But should governments step in to provide news as a public good? Here lies the dilemma. State provision creates a monopoly, a single “firm” supplying news, leaving it inelastic and prone to manipulation. Even if funded by taxes, the burden is shifted onto citizens, lowering disposable income. Reduced spending can spark a chain reaction: weaker demand, reduced production, higher unemployment, and possible deflation. In other words, funding truth might inadvertently distort markets.

One possible model begins at the grassroots, with governments setting up information centres in villages and districts, ensuring local voices are heard and content is not overlooked. Central teams of editors, journalists, and experts would then filter content for relevance, but sensitive news may be postponed to prevent unrest. Excessive caution, however, risks violating rights and undermining trust. Finally, the problem of distribution remains pressing: how high-quality journalism reaches all citizens in societies divided by access to technology and literacy. Modernity offers many channels of communication but not all are accessible to everyone. The economics of journalism is now entangled with technology policy, algorithms that amplify misinformation, AI-driven deepfakes, and the monopolisation of digital platforms.
This is not a purely national problem but a global one. In Asia, India grapples with misinformation during elections. In Europe, public broadcasters such as the BBC face constant debates about taxpayer funding. In North America, advertising-driven outlets struggle to balance profit with independence. The Middle East faces censorship alongside state-funded megaphones. In Africa, funding shortages threaten journalistic survival, while in authoritarian regimes the media remains captive. Globally, the business model of news—advertising, subscriptions, or taxation—is also a business strategy question. Media houses, like firms, must decide whether to maximise reach, credibility, or revenue. Investors, too, weigh these trade-offs, since media credibility directly affects market stability, investor confidence, and even the pricing of assets.

The economics of truth is complicated. Journalism clearly functions as a public good, generating benefits far beyond private consumption. But state provision risks monopoly, censorship, and unintended macroeconomic consequences. Perhaps the lesson is this: accurate news is both an economic stabiliser and a political safeguard. Taxpayer funding might provide short-term relief, but unless accompanied by institutional safeguards, it risks weakening the very independence that makes journalism valuable. The challenge is to design a system where media remains free, sustainable, and accessible—without collapsing into either market failure or state capture.